Sharing tomorrow's ideas. Today.
Maintain multi-currency system or return to local currency…?
A few days ago, Alex Magaisa challenged Economists to give a nuanced perspective on the implications of the decision taken in 2009 by the Government of Zimbabwe to abolish its domestic currency, the Zimbabwean dollar (ZWD), in favor of a basket of other currencies including the United States dollar (USD) and the South African Rand (ZAR) - a process known as currency substitution. He further questioned the long-term prospects of that strategy and whether concerns over a return to a local currency, under whatever name, as legal tender are justifiable.
Zimbabwe’s currency substitution process was not prepense government planning. The Government was ‘forced’ into this position after it became apparent that private transactions were no longer being conducted in ZWD and that the bulk of transactions were taking place on the ‘parallel market,’ with the ZWD only accepted in government institutions. The move by individuals and private businesses to shun the ZWD as a medium of exchange of value was of course forced by hyperinflation, which peaked at a staggering 76 billion percent in 2008.
In 2009, recognising the futility of continuing with a currency that was no longer legitimate, the Government of Zimbabwe took a unilateral decision to adopt a multi-currency system. This is the system that is in operation today.
Six years on, opinion is divided between those who believe Zimbabwe should maintain a multi-currency system and those who want a return to a local currency, whichever name it might be called. Those who wish to sustain currency substitution base their belief in lessons from the past: Zimbabwe abolished its currency as a measure to deal with risks of rapid devaluation, exchange rate uncertainty for Zimbabwean businesses and exchange rate transaction costs for both businesses and tourists.
In many ways therefore, they argue, currency substitution has delivered stable and well-aligned exchange rates, macroeconomic stability and an increase in economic welfare for the ordinary Zimbabwean. As such, ditching the multi-currency system now would be a mistake, particularly in the absence of meaningful reversal of what triggered the hyperinflation in the first place.
In contrast, those who believe in a return to domestic currency accept that as a result of currency substitution Zimbabwe has now gained significant macroeconomic stability. However, growing the economy and building on that gain is proving difficult largely because the lack of exchange rate removes a very effective mechanism for stimulating the economy and increasing exports through currency devaluation. In the absence of such a mechanism, they claim, Zimbabwe will likely be increasingly uncompetitive and unable to cope with differential shocks affecting Zimbabwe and its trading partners.
As such, they conclude, a return to the ZWD could alleviate the economic costs and risks arising from losing the option to devalue the domestic currency in order to restore international competitiveness.
Do these arguments have a credible basis?
Giving up a national currency is not a uniquely Zimbabwean phenomenon. Several countries have adopted the strategy with mostly positive outcomes. Panama in South America currently uses the USD and countries in the Sterling currency area (United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland) use the British pound. Similarly, the Euro-zone represents a single currency arrangement that came into effective operation on January 1st 2002, when 12 EU members got rid of their own currencies and introduced the Euro as their sole currency.
The assertion that currency substitution has been largely positive is correct. Sustained low-inflation has helped dramatically reduce long-term interest rates and stimulate some economic growth and competitiveness. Zimbabwe’s annual percentage growth rate of GDP surged from minus 17% in 2008, to 6% (2009); 11.4% (2010); 11.9% (2011); 10.6% (2012); 4.5% (2013) through to 3.2% in 2014. No doubt, the move created opportunity for some Zimbabweans, increased business confidence and enabled more effective and predictable planning.
So high is the confidence in this strategy that the Minister of Finance recently declared that a return to the ZWD is not imminent.
For others, the transition to a dollarized economy has caused discomfort – particularly to those whose stocks were denominated in ZWD. However, as most transactions were already dominated in US dollars, the demise of ZWD did not produce totally unfamiliar circumstances. In fact it created conditions for price transparency and brought some credibility to financial planning processes – with investment and growth being obvious beneficial consequences.
The country is now facing a myriad of problems. From 2012 to date, the economy has been shrinking: Productivity is low; Overall exports, save for those from the mining industry, are low; Credit is almost non-existent (and where available, the interest rates are near-extortion!); and Prices of goods and services are rising. High operating costs and low effective demand are forcing some businesses to shut down. The promise of multi-currency system is waning. Attempts by the Zimbabwean government to introduce an economic policy to fight back against unemployment, such as ZIMASSET, are bearing no fruit.
Effectively, the option of rebooting the economy out of difficulties through well-chosen devaluation is no longer available to Zimbabwe. And that has strengthened the arguments for stepping away from the multi-currency system.
So who is right?
Zimbabwe finds itself on the horns of a dilemma on this issue. The Zimbabwe experience certainly suggests that currency substitution can offer economic benefits – but only under fortunate circumstances. And Zimbabwe’s circumstances are far from fortunate.
So what to do?
To return to Alex Magaisa’s question, while concerns over a return to a local currency or the adoption of a multi-currency system are often portrayed as an economic governance problem, their roots are in our politics and democratic practice. At the core of the problem is a massive loss of credibility in Zimbabwe’s monetary (and political?) institutions as well as a growing trust gap between the public and regulatory institutions. It is our politics and practice, including many years of fiscal indiscipline, political interference and imprudent monetary choices that are undermining public trust. In some ways therefore, discussing the replacement of multi-currency system is a distraction that may let the Finance Minister, and Zimbabwe Government as a whole, off easy from the real issue of creating an environment conducive to good economic governance and performance.
Finally, as previously mentioned, the emergence of the ‘parallel market’ forced the Government’s hand towards adopting a multi-currency system. The implication here is that, in the absence of trust and confidence in governance institutions, even if the Government of Zimbabwe were to re-introduce a new local currency, it would find it difficult and impractical to force people to accept that currency in private transactions. Hence, to be sure, at least for now, the multi-currency system is the least harmful option.
Maxwell Gomera
Latest comments
10.08 | 16:04
Continue to rest in peace sekuru
10.08 | 07:11
Till we meet again keep resting in peace sekuru
05.07 | 09:26
Isitshwala, the food of champions! You took me down memory lane with this piece, my friend. And with a smile too!!
21.06 | 10:01
RIP will always be missed